OPINION

Cognitive Dissonance on Health Care Reform

The opinions expressed by columnists are their own and do not necessarily represent the views of Townhall.com.

Cognitive dissonance is defined as holding two completely contradictory ideas at the same time. 

That seems to be the case with the American public, with a new poll showing rising support for a so-called public option in health care, even as the public continues to oppose greater government control over the health care system. 

Going Rogue by Sarah Palin FREE

Most likely that is because supporters of a public option have successfully framed it as just that: an option.  That seems entirely reasonable.  The American people believe in “choice” and “competition.”  So why not allow another choice?  Most Americans would keep the insurance they have today (and are happy with), but those who wanted to join the government plan could do so. 

But that’s not the way it would actually work.

A government-run plan would have an inherent advantage in the marketplace, because it ultimately would be subsidized by taxpayers. The government plan could keep its premiums artificially low or offer extra benefits, because it could turn to taxpayers to cover any shortfalls.  At the very least, the program carries with it an implicit guarantee against future losses.  Would a Congress that has bailed out banks and automobile companies because they are "too big to fail" resist subsidizing the government's insurance plan if it began to lose money?

Even without direct subsidies, the government could prevent the true cost of the program from showing up in premium prices in myriad ways.  For example, the government-run plan will not have to pay state or federal taxes, and unlike private insurance plans, who can be sued in state courts, the government-run plan could only be sued in federal court.

Government plans such as Medicare and Medicaid traditionally reimburse providers at rates considerably lower than those of private insurance.  Providers recoup the lost income by shifting costs onto those with private insurance.  Indeed, it is estimated that privately insured patients pay $89 billion annually in additional insurance costs because of cost-shifting from government programs. If one assumes that the new public option has similar reimbursement policies, it would both allow the public plan to keep its own premiums artificially low while simultaneously increasing costs and, therefore, premium prices for private insurance. 

All of this means that the government-run plan would be significantly cheaper than private insurance, not because it would out-compete private insurance or because it was more efficient, but because it had unfair advantages.   Businesses, in particular, would have every incentive to dump their workers into the government plan. 

Estimates of how many people would ultimately be forced out of their current insurance and into the government plan vary widely.  At the low end, the Congressional Budget Office suggests that about three million people would be involuntarily shifted to the government plan under the House bill.  It bases this estimate on a premise that that the plan would only be open to the currently uninsured and employers with fewer than 50 employees.  On the other hand, the actuarial firm Lewin Associates assumes that the government plan would be open to everyone.  Under that scenario, they suggest, 89.5 million workers would be forced into the government plan. 

In the end, the private insurance market would be eviscerated, leaving millions of Americans with no choice but the government-run program. No choice. No competition.  We would effectively be on the road to a single-payer health care system, with the government in complete control of one-sixth of the U.S. health care system and some of the most important, personal, and private decisions in our lives.  Down that road lie massive new taxes, huge budget deficits, and ultimately government rationing of care.

That is not what the American people are telling pollsters they support.